Monetary Policy Report - August 2024

Our quarterly Monetary Policy Report sets out the economic analysis and inflation projections that the Monetary Policy Committee uses to make its interest rate decisions.
Published on 01 August 2024

Over the past couple of years we have raised to slow down price rises (). It’s working. Inflation has fallen a lot over the past 18 months. Inflation in the UK fell back to our 2% target in May and June. In part due to the fading impacts of global shocks like the war in Ukraine and Covid. In part due to higher interest rates.

Inflationary pressures have now eased enough that we’ve been able to cut interest rates today.

But this decision was finely balanced. The risks of higher inflation remain. We need to make sure inflation stays low. So we have to be careful not to cut interest rates too much or too quickly.

We expect inflation to rise again this year, to around 2¾%. But we expect this increase to be temporary with inflation coming back down next year. Over the coming years we need to make sure that inflation will continue to stay low. High inflation has affected everyone, but it particularly hurts those who can least afford it. 

This video requires third-party analytical cookies to play. Read our cookie policy for more information.

Higher interest rates have helped return inflation to target but it is likely to rise temporarily.

Our job is to make sure that inflation stays at our target. 

We’ve been using higher interest rates for the past couple of years to help slow down price rises. This is working, inflation was at 2% in May and June.

Higher interest rates work by reducing demand for goods and services in the economy. This helps slow the rate of inflation. 

Inflation has fallen to its lowest level since September 2021

Progress on inflation means we have been able to reduce interest rates today.

Inflation has fallen back to 2%. The progress we have made on inflation means that we’ve been able to cut interest rates to 5% today.

Nevertheless, inflation is likely to rise to around 2¾% in the second half of the year, as household energy prices provide less of a drag on inflation than they have done in recent months. 

But we expect this to be only a temporary rise, with inflation falling back to around our target afterwards.

We expect inflation to rise again temporarily before settling back down

We need to make sure inflation stays low. We will not cut rates too much or too quickly.

Today’s decision was finely balanced. We will need to make sure inflation stays low in the years to come.

Despite overall inflation being at target, prices of some items are still rising quickly. Prices of services – for example hotels and restaurants, insurance and rents for housing – are still rising at rates well above their past averages. 

Furthermore, at the start of this year demand for goods and services in the economy has been stronger than we expected. If this stronger demand were to continue, this could lead to higher inflation. 

We need to put the period of high inflation firmly behind us. And we need to be careful not to cut rates too much or too quickly. We will consider whether or not to cut interest rates further at future meetings. 

The best contribution the Bank can make to support economic growth and people’s prosperity is by making sure we have low and stable inflation. 

We have cut interest rates to 5%

Monetary Policy Report

Monetary Policy Summary

The Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) sets monetary policy to meet the 2% inflation target, and in a way that helps to sustain growth and employment. The MPC adopts a medium-term and forward-looking approach to determine the monetary stance required to achieve the inflation target sustainably.

At its meeting ending on 31 July 2024, the MPC voted by a majority of 5–4 to reduce Bank Rate by 0.25 percentage points, to 5%. Four members preferred to maintain Bank Rate at 5.25%.

The Committee has published an updated set of projections for activity and inflation in the accompanying August Monetary Policy Report.

Twelve-month CPI inflation was at the MPC’s 2% target in both May and June. CPI inflation is expected to increase to around 2¾% in the second half of this year, as declines in energy prices last year fall out of the annual comparison, revealing more clearly the prevailing persistence of domestic inflationary pressures. Private sector regular average weekly earnings growth has fallen to 5.6% in the three months to May, and services consumer price inflation has declined to 5.7% in June. GDP has picked up quite sharply so far this year, but underlying momentum appears weaker.

The Committee’s framework for assessing the medium-term outlook for inflation distinguishes between first and second-round effects. The MPC has been focused on second-round effects that capture more persistent inflationary pressures. The Committee continues to monitor the accumulation of evidence from a broad range of indicators.

The Committee expects the fall in headline inflation, and normalisation in many indicators of inflation expectations, to continue to feed through to weaker pay and price-setting dynamics. A margin of slack should emerge in the economy as GDP falls below potential and the labour market eases further. Domestic inflationary persistence is expected to fade away over the next few years, owing to the restrictive stance of monetary policy.

However, there is a risk that inflationary pressures from second-round effects will prove more enduring in the medium term. A stronger-than-expected path for demand, and structural factors such as a higher equilibrium rate of unemployment, could affect domestic wage and price-setting more persistently. Furthermore, the degree of restrictiveness of monetary policy could be less than embodied in the Committee’s current assessment.

In balancing these considerations, at this meeting, the Committee voted to reduce Bank Rate to 5%. It is now appropriate to reduce slightly the degree of policy restrictiveness. The impact from past external shocks has abated and there has been some progress in moderating risks of persistence in inflation. Although GDP has been stronger than expected, the restrictive stance of monetary policy continues to weigh on activity in the real economy, leading to a looser labour market and bearing down on inflationary pressures.

Monetary policy will need to continue to remain restrictive for sufficiently long until the risks to inflation returning sustainably to the 2% target in the medium term have dissipated further. The Committee continues to monitor closely the risks of inflation persistence and will decide the appropriate degree of monetary policy restrictiveness at each meeting.

1: The economic outlook

Twelve-month CPI inflation was at the MPC’s 2% target in May and June, close to the projection in the May Monetary Policy Report. GDP has picked up quite sharply so far this year, but underlying momentum appears weaker.

Four-quarter GDP growth is expected to fall back a little next year in the Committee’s modal or most likely projection, but then increase again over the remainder of the forecast period, to around 1¾% (Key judgement 1). That pickup in part reflects the fading negative impact on growth from past increases in Bank Rate and the downward-sloping market-implied path of forward interest rates, which begin to boost growth towards the end of the period. The risks around the modal projection for GDP growth are skewed slightly to the upside over the first two years of the forecast period.

In the modal projection, aggregate demand and supply are judged to be broadly in balance currently, but a margin of economic slack is projected to emerge during 2025 and to remain thereafter, reflecting the continued restrictive stance of monetary policy (Key judgement 2). Unemployment is expected to rise somewhat. The risks around the modal output gap projection are judged to be skewed to the upside in part reflecting the possibility of a higher medium-term equilibrium rate of unemployment pushing down on supply relative to demand.

CPI inflation is expected to increase to around 2¾% in the second half of this year as declines in energy prices last year fall out of the annual comparison, revealing more clearly the prevailing persistence of domestic inflationary pressures (Chart 1.1). The Committee continues to expect second-round effects in domestic prices and wages to take longer to unwind than they did to emerge (Key judgement 3). There remains considerable uncertainty around the calibration of this judgement and a range of views among MPC members about the extent to which persistent pressures prove more enduring or continue to unwind as external cost pressures and inflation expectations have normalised.

In the MPC’s modal projection conditioned on the market-implied path of interest rates, CPI inflation falls back to 1.7% in two years’ time and to 1.5% in three years, reflecting the continued restrictive stance of monetary policy and the emergence of a margin of slack in the economy. The risks around the modal CPI projection are skewed somewhat to the upside throughout the forecast period, reflecting more persistence in domestic wage and price-setting. That could reflect more structural factors such as the possibility of a higher equilibrium rate of unemployment. Mean CPI inflation is 2.0% and 1.8% at the two and three-year horizons respectively.

Table 1.A: Forecast summary (a) (b)

2024 Q3

2025 Q3

2026 Q3

2027 Q3

GDP (c)

1.5 (0.5)

0.8 (0.9)

1.4 (1.3)

1.7

Modal CPI inflation (d)

2.3 (2.2)

2.4 (2.5)

1.7 (1.8)

1.5

Mean CPI inflation (d)

2.3 (2.4)

2.5 (2.6)

2.0 (1.8)

1.8

Unemployment rate (e)

4.4 (4.3)

4.6 (4.7)

4.8 (4.9)

4.6

Excess supply/Excess demand (f)

0 (-¼)

-1 (-1)

-1¼ (-1¼)

Bank Rate (g)

5.1 (5.0)

4.2 (4.4)

3.8 (3.9)

3.5

Footnotes

  • (a) Figures in parentheses show the corresponding projections in the May 2024 Monetary Policy Report.
  • (b) Unless otherwise stated, the numbers shown in this table are modal projections and are conditioned on the assumptions described in Section 1.1.
  • (c) Four-quarter growth in real GDP.
  • (d) Four-quarter inflation rate. The modal projection is the single most likely outcome. If the risks are symmetrically distributed around this central view, this will also provide a view of the average outcome or mean forecast. But when the risks are skewed, as in the current forecast, the mean projection will differ from the mode.
  • (e) ILO definition of unemployment. Although LFS unemployment data have been re-instated by the ONS, they are badged as official statistics in development and the LFS continues to suffer from very low response rates, which can introduce volatility and potentially non-response bias (see Box D in the May 2024 Monetary Policy Report).
  • (f) Per cent of potential GDP. A negative figure implies output is below potential and a positive that it is above.
  • (g) Per cent. The path for Bank Rate implied by forward market interest rates. The curves are based on overnight index swap rates.

Chart 1.1: CPI inflation and CPI inflation excluding energy (a)

Energy prices are currently reducing inflation, but that drag is waning, leading to a rise in inflation in the second half of 2024

Footnotes

  • Sources: Bloomberg Finance L.P., ONS and Bank calculations.
  • (a) Energy prices include fuels and lubricants, electricity, gas and other fuels.

1.1: The conditioning assumptions underlying the MPC’s projections

As set out in Table 1.B, the MPC’s August projections are conditioned on:

  • The paths for policy rates in advanced economies implied by financial markets, as captured in the 15 working day averages of forward interest rates to 22 July (Chart 2.7). The market-implied path for Bank Rate underpinning the August projections declines to around 3½% by the end of the three-year forecast period, compared with an endpoint of around 3¾% in the May Report.
  • A path for the sterling effective exchange rate index that is around 2½% higher compared with the May Report. The exchange rate depreciates slightly over the forecast period, reflecting the role of expected interest rate differentials in the Committee’s conditioning assumption.
  • Wholesale energy prices that follow their respective futures curves over the forecast period. Since May, oil prices have fallen, while gas futures prices are slightly higher. Uncertainty remains around the outlook for wholesale energy prices, including related to geopolitical developments.
  • UK household energy prices that move in line with Bank staff estimates of the Ofgem price cap implied by the paths of wholesale gas and electricity prices (Section 2.4).
  • Fiscal policy that evolves in line with UK government policies to date, as announced in Spring Budget 2024. The Government has announced that any changes in the stance of fiscal policy will be set out in the Budget on 30 October. These will be incorporated in the November Monetary Policy Report projections.

Table 1.B: Conditioning assumptions (a) (b)

Average 1998–2007

Average 2010–19

2022

2023

2024

2025

2026

Bank Rate (c)

5.0

0.5

2.8

5.3

4.9 (4.8)

4.1 (4.3)

3.7 (3.8)

Sterling effective exchange rate (d)

100

82

78

81

84 (82)

84 (82)

83 (81)

Oil prices (e)

39

77

89

84

83 (85)

78 (79)

75 (75)

Gas prices (f)

29

52

201

101

92 (88)

95 (91)

84 (79)

Nominal government expenditure (g)

4

7.0

2¾ (2½)

2¼ (2½)

2¾ (2¾)

Footnotes

  • Sources: Bank of England, Bloomberg Finance L.P., LSEG Workspace, Office for Budget Responsibility (OBR), ONS and Bank calculations.
  • (a) The table shows the projections for financial market prices, wholesale energy prices and government spending projections that are used as conditioning assumptions for the MPC’s projections for CPI inflation, GDP growth and the unemployment rate. Figures in parentheses show the corresponding projections in the May 2024 Report.
  • (b) Financial market data are based on averages in the 15 working days to 22 July 2024. Figures show the average level in Q4 of each year, unless otherwise stated.
  • (c) Per cent. The path for Bank Rate implied by forward market interest rates. The curves are based on overnight index swap rates.
  • (d) Index. January 2005 = 100. The convention is that the sterling exchange rate follows a path that is halfway between the starting level of the sterling ERI and a path implied by interest rate differentials.
  • (e) Dollars per barrel. Projection based on monthly Brent futures prices.
  • (f) Pence per therm. Projection based on monthly natural gas futures prices.
  • (g) Annual average growth rate. Nominal general government consumption and investment. Projections are based on the OBR’s March 2024 Economic and Fiscal Outlook. Historical data based on NMRP+D7QK.

1.2: Key judgements and risks

1.2: Key judgement 1

Activity has picked up quite sharply so far this year, but underlying momentum appears weaker. Four-quarter GDP growth is expected to fall back a little next year in the Committee’s modal or most likely projection, but then increase again over the remainder of the forecast period, to around 1¾%.

Following weakness last year, UK GDP increased by 0.7% in 2024 Q1 and is now expected to have risen by 0.7% in Q2 (Section 2.3), compared with projections of 0.4% and 0.2% respectively in the May Report. Based on readings from business surveys, underlying momentum in activity is judged to be weaker than headline GDP growth. Quarterly GDP growth is expected to fall back to 0.4% in 2024 Q3 and to 0.2% in Q4, broadly consistent with the current signal from surveys.

The MPC’s August projections are conditioned on fiscal policy that evolves in line with UK government policies, as announced in Spring Budget 2024. After taking account of those plans and of the fading impact of past loosening measures, the stance of fiscal policy tightens over the forecast period. This pulls down on the Committee’s GDP growth projection beyond the near term.

Box C in this Report sets out the latest evidence on the transmission of higher Bank Rate to GDP through the domestic economy. Based on the average relationships over the past between Bank Rate and economic activity, Bank staff estimate that under the current market-implied path for interest rates, including its expected impact on broader financial conditions, most of the domestic impact of higher interest rates since the middle of 2021 on the level of GDP should be expected to have come through. The remaining impact is likely to drag further on the level of GDP in the near term.

Growth rates across advanced economies have generally converged at the start of this year (Section 2.1). UK-weighted world GDP increased by 0.5% in 2024 Q1 and is projected to grow at a similar pace for the rest of this year. In the August Report, the path of global growth is broadly unchanged from May, although the path of world trade is somewhat stronger during the middle of the forecast period reflecting developments in the euro area. Four-quarter UK-weighted world GDP growth is projected to rise to just over 2% in the medium term, slightly below its average rate in the decade prior to the pandemic (Table 1.D).

Overall, in the Committee’s August modal or most likely projection, UK four-quarter GDP growth is projected to fall back a little next year but then increase again over the remainder of the forecast period, to around 1¾% (Chart 1.2). That pickup in part reflects the fading negative impact on growth from past increases in Bank Rate and the downward-sloping market-implied path of forward interest rates, which begin to boost growth towards the end of the period. Notwithstanding the higher starting point, the pace of GDP growth in the August projection is broadly similar to the May Report over much of the forecast period.

Within the key private domestic expenditure components underpinning the August modal GDP projection (Table 1.D), household spending growth is expected to be only slightly positive this calendar year, although this in large part reflects the effect on the annual average of declines in consumption in 2023 H2. Spending is expected to increase steadily throughout the forecast period. The saving ratio is expected to peak at around 12% of household income in 2024 Q3, before falling back over the remainder of the forecast period. Following a period of pronounced weakness in 2023, housing investment is expected to grow moderately over the forecast period, stronger than expected in the May Report. Business investment is projected to grow by around 2% on a year earlier throughout much of the forecast period, a smoother profile than in May.

Chart 1.2: GDP growth projection based on market interest rate expectations, other policy measures as announced

Shaded fan chart for the four-quarter G D P growth projection (wide bands). There is uncertainty around the O N S data, because they may be revised over time. The distribution widens over the forecast period to reflect uncertainty around the outlook for G D P

Footnotes

  • The fan chart depicts the probability of various outcomes for GDP growth. It has been conditioned on Bank Rate following a path implied by market yields, but allows the Committee’s judgement on the risks around the other conditioning assumptions set out in Section 1.1, including wholesale energy prices, to affect the calibration of the fan chart skew. To the left of the shaded area, the distribution reflects uncertainty around revisions to the data over the past. To the right of the shaded area, the distribution reflects uncertainty over the evolution of GDP growth in the future. If economic circumstances identical to today’s were to prevail on 100 occasions, the MPC’s best collective judgement is that the mature estimate of GDP growth would lie within the darkest central band on only 30 of those occasions. The fan chart is constructed so that outturns are also expected to lie within each pair of the lighter aqua areas on 30 occasions. In any particular quarter of the forecast period, GDP growth is therefore expected to lie somewhere within the fan on 90 out of 100 occasions. And on the remaining 10 out of 100 occasions GDP growth can fall anywhere outside the aqua area of the fan chart. Over the forecast period, this has been depicted by the grey background. See the Box on page 39 of the November 2007 Inflation Report for a fuller description of the fan chart and what it represents. The y-axis of the chart has been truncated to illustrate more clearly the current uncertainty around the path of GDP growth, as otherwise this would be obscured by the volatility of GDP growth during the pandemic.

In the modal GDP projection conditioned on the alternative assumption of constant interest rates at 5% over the forecast period, growth is weaker compared with the MPC’s projection conditioned on the declining path of market-implied rates.

The risks around the modal projection for GDP growth are judged to be skewed slightly to the upside over the first two years of the forecast period.

There are risks in both directions around the central projections for UK GDP and, for a given path of potential supply, around the output gap (Key judgement 2).

Internationally, the continuing risk of higher commodity prices and disruption to trade flows associated with developments in the Middle East could, alongside other significant geopolitical uncertainties, lead to weaker economic activity as well as greater external inflationary pressures (Key judgement 3). There remains a downside risk to global growth if domestic demand in China proves to be softer than expected. In the other direction, there may be a near-term upside risk to global activity if the recent resilience of advanced-economy labour markets were to persist, although that could also lead the stance of monetary policy to be more restrictive than otherwise. There is also uncertainty around the path of fiscal policy in advanced economies.

As discussed in Box C, there is some evidence that the impact of increases in Bank Rate on UK GDP has peaked a little earlier and at a smaller level than in the estimates underpinning the Committee’s August central projection. It is also possible that the equilibrium real interest rate has risen somewhat, such that the stance of monetary policy is less restrictive than assumed (see Box C in the February 2024 Report). All else equal, these risks could imply a stronger path of demand over the forecast period. The Committee’s forecast has for some time, however, incorporated a judgement to boost the expected path of demand relative to its standard determinants, and so it is also possible that a slightly faster or weaker monetary transmission mechanism in this rate tightening cycle rationalises part of this judgement and so is already captured indirectly in the August central projection. The Committee will continue to monitor closely the impact of past changes in Bank Rate.

Overall, the risks around the modal projection for UK GDP growth are skewed slightly to the upside over the first two years of the forecast period, allowing some of the recent momentum in domestic demand to continue for longer. This pushes up on the mean, relative to the modal, growth projections in the forecast. All else equal, this would also reduce slightly the degree of excess supply in the modal output gap projection (Key judgement 2) and hence increase domestic inflationary pressures slightly relative to the modal CPI projection (Key judgement 3).

1.2: Key judgement 2

In the Committee’s modal projection, aggregate demand and supply are judged to be broadly in balance currently, but a margin of economic slack is projected to emerge during 2025 and to remain thereafter, in part reflecting the continued restrictive stance of monetary policy. Unemployment is expected to rise somewhat.

Following a period in 2021 and 2022 in which the economy was operating with excess demand, aggregate demand and supply are judged to have been broadly in balance by the end of last year.

Given the upside news on GDP expected over the first three quarters of 2024, the Committee has considered carefully the extent to which this reflects developments in the balance of aggregate demand and supply. In general, the MPC’s approach is to calibrate its judgement on the starting level of the output gap based on a range of data and modelling approaches, including the extent to which news in GDP is consistent with developments in capacity utilisation, labour market tightness and other domestic inflationary pressures in the economy. In recent forecast rounds, GDP has first surprised to the downside and, more recently, to the upside (Annex 2). Indicators of utilisation and tightness have moved by much less across this period and, as a result, the Committee judges that the output gap has been more stable than movements in the GDP data might otherwise imply.

The MPC is continuing to consider the collective steer from a wide range of data to inform its view on labour market developments. As discussed in Box D in the May 2024 Monetary Policy Report and the June 2024 MPC Minutes, there remains considerable uncertainty around statistics derived from the ONS Labour Force Survey, making it more difficult to gauge the underlying state of labour market activity.

Based on a broad set of indicators, the MPC continues to judge that the labour market is loosening but that it remains relatively tight by historical standards (Section 2.3). Bank staff estimates suggest that the unemployment rate has been broadly stable over the past few quarters at a level somewhat below the LFS measure, which has risen to 4.4%. The number of vacancies and the vacancies to unemployment ratio have fallen further, the latter returning to around its pre-pandemic level. Underlying employment growth is estimated to have been stronger than LFS employment over the past few quarters, and to have been broadly in line with population growth. To the extent that businesses responded to weakness in GDP in the second half of last year by retaining their existing employees and using them somewhat less intensively, the recent strength of GDP growth has been accommodated without the need for businesses to increase headcount significantly.

Overall, the Committee judges in its modal projection that the margin of spare capacity in the economy is only slightly reduced at the start of this forecast compared with the May projection, and that demand and supply have remained broadly in balance so far this year.

The Committee has not adjusted its expectation of potential supply growth in this Report beyond the first half of this year. Four-quarter supply growth is projected to average around 1½% during the second and third years of the forecast period.

As in previous forecasts, demand growth is expected to be weaker than potential supply growth during 2025, such that a margin of economic slack is projected to emerge in the Committee’s modal projection. That in part reflects the continued restrictive stance of monetary policy, alongside the assumed tightening in the stance of fiscal policy. Aggregate excess supply is expected to reach around 1¼% of potential GDP by the end of 2025, broadly similar to the May Report. Thereafter, demand growth is expected to be slightly stronger than supply growth, such that the margin of economic slack starts to narrow gradually.

Uncertainty around LFS data notwithstanding, the unemployment rate is projected to rise somewhat during the second year of the forecast period, such that it exceeds the assumed medium-term equilibrium rate of around 4½% by the middle of next year. The unemployment rate reaches around 4¾% by the end of 2025 (Chart 1.3), broadly similar to the May Report, and remains around that level thereafter.

Chart 1.3: Unemployment rate projection based on market interest rate expectations, other policy measures as announced

Shaded fan chart for the unemployment rate projection. The distribution widens over the forecast period.

Footnotes

  • The fan chart depicts the probability of various future outcomes for the ILO definition of unemployment and begins in 2024 Q2. Although LFS unemployment data have recently been re-instated by the ONS, they are badged as official statistics in development and the LFS continues to suffer from very low response rates, which can introduce volatility and potentially non-response bias (see Box D in the May 2024 Monetary Policy Report). The fan chart has been conditioned on Bank Rate following a path implied by market yields, but allows the Committee’s judgement on the risks around the other conditioning assumptions set out in Section 1.1, including wholesale energy prices, to affect the calibration of the fan chart skew. The coloured bands have the same interpretation as in Chart 1.2 and portray 90% of the probability distribution. A significant proportion of this distribution lies below Bank staff’s current estimate of the long-term equilibrium unemployment rate. There is therefore uncertainty about the precise calibration of this fan chart.

In the modal projection conditioned on the alternative assumption of constant interest rates at 5% over the forecast period, the unemployment rate rises to a greater extent compared with the projection conditioned on market rates.

The risks around the modal output gap projection are judged to be skewed to the upside.

The Committee recognises the significant uncertainty around real-time estimates of the output gap, including the extent to which recent upside news in GDP could represent the re-emergence of a small margin of excess demand in the economy. All else equal, further positive surprises in activity data or signs of weakness in the supply side of the economy would suggest an upside risk around the Committee’s central projection for the output gap and hence greater domestic inflationary pressures (Key judgement 3). Set against that, external forecasters generally assume that there has been a greater margin of spare capacity in the economy recently.

Reflecting the continuing uncertainties around interpreting estimates from the LFS, there are risks in both directions around the recent path of the unemployment rate, and hence the outlook for unemployment and labour market tightness. The labour market could remain tighter or looser than assumed for a number of economic reasons, including the risks around the outlook for demand (Key judgement 1).

There is also continuing significant uncertainty around the MPC’s assumption for the path of the equilibrium rate of unemployment, news in which would, holding demand fixed, have implications for labour market tightness and inflationary pressures. The Committee made an upward adjustment to the medium-term equilibrium rate in the November 2023 Report, reflecting a greater degree of real income resistance following the terms of trade shock to the economy. It remains possible that the equilibrium rate of unemployment is even higher, consistent with more persistence in future wage growth. There has, however, been some evidence of a normalisation in the Beveridge curve relationship between the vacancies and unemployment rates that could imply a lower equilibrium unemployment rate if it were to continue.

Overall, the risks around the modal projection for the output gap are skewed to the upside at the start of and throughout the forecast period. This can be accounted for in part by the positive skew that has been incorporated into the GDP growth projection (Key judgement 1) but to a larger extent by the possibility of a higher medium-term equilibrium rate of unemployment pushing down on supply relative to demand. All else equal, this increases domestic inflationary pressures relative to the modal CPI projection (Key judgement 3).

1.2: Key judgement 3

CPI inflation is expected to increase to around 2¾% in the second half of this year as declines in energy prices last year fall out of the annual comparison, revealing more clearly the prevailing persistence of domestic inflationary pressures. The Committee continues to expect second-round effects in domestic prices and wages to take longer to unwind than they did to emerge.

Twelve-month CPI inflation was at the MPC’s 2% target in May and June, close to the projection in the May Report. The decline in CPI inflation since the start of this year has primarily reflected lower goods price inflation, alongside a small fall in services price inflation. Many indicators of household and business inflation expectations have normalised to around their 2010–19 averages (Section 2.4).

CPI inflation is projected to increase in 2024 Q3 and in Q4, to around 2¾%, similar to the May Report. This profile of inflation over the second half of the year is accounted for largely by developments in the direct energy price contribution to 12-month CPI inflation, which is projected to become less negative during Q3 and Q4 compared with Q2 (Chart 1.1). CPI inflation excluding energy is projected to be around 3¼% during the second half of the year, revealing more clearly the prevailing persistence of domestic inflationary pressures.

Four-quarter UK-weighted world export price inflation, excluding the direct effect of oil prices, was negative at the end of last year, but is since expected to have picked up (Section 2.1). Over the forecast period, the recent appreciation of the sterling exchange rate and its assumed path is likely to put some downward pressure on UK import price inflation, and over time on CPI inflation, relative to the May Report. Import prices are projected to fall by ¾% in 2024 and by 1% in 2025 (Table 1.D). The Committee has retained its judgement from the May Report that a greater-than-usual proportion of the pass-through of previous large-scale increases in import prices to consumer goods prices has occurred already.

The MPC has been monitoring closely indications of persistent inflationary pressures and resilience in the UK economy as a whole, including a range of measures of the underlying tightness of labour market conditions (Key judgement 2), wage growth and services price inflation.

Annual private sector regular AWE growth declined to 5.6% in the three months to May, in line with expectations in the May Report, and broadly in line with alternative indicators of wage growth. The Bank’s Agents report that pay settlements will average just over 5½% this year, with tentative expectations of lower settlements for 2025 (Box E). Private sector regular AWE growth is expected to slow further in the near term, to around 5% during the rest of this year, similar to the May Report.

Services CPI inflation has declined to 5.7% in June, higher than expected in the May 2024 Report. Services CPI inflation is expected to continue to ease only gradually over the course of this year, as wage growth weakens further.

In the August modal projection for CPI inflation, the Committee has maintained its broad judgement that second-round effects in wages and domestic prices will take longer to unwind than they did to emerge. There remains considerable uncertainty around the calibration of this judgement and a range of views among MPC members about the extent to which persistent pressures prove more enduring or continue to unwind as external cost pressures and inflation expectations have normalised (as set out in the subsequent risks sub-section). The Committee is also considering the interactions between the outlook for demand, the margin of spare capacity in the economy (Key judgement 2) and its judgement on excess persistence.

In the MPC’s modal projection conditioned on the market-implied path of interest rates as captured in the 15-working day average to 22 July, CPI inflation increases from the 2% target to around 2¾% at the turn of the year. Reflecting the continued restrictive stance of monetary policy and the emergence of a margin of slack in the economy (Key judgement 2), CPI inflation then falls back again, to 1.7% in two years’ time and to 1.5% in three years (Table 1.C and Chart 1.4). The August CPI inflation projection is similar to the May projection. Private sector regular AWE growth is expected to fall further during 2025 and reaches just under 3% towards the end of the forecast period, very similar to the May Report.

Chart 1.4: CPI inflation projection based on market interest rate expectations, other policy measures as announced

Shaded fan chart for the C P I inflation projection (wide bands). The distribution widens over the forecast period to reflect uncertainty around the outlook for the modal inflation projection.

Footnotes

  • The fan chart depicts the probability of various future outcomes for CPI inflation and begins in 2024 Q3. It has been conditioned on Bank Rate following a path implied by market yields, but allows the Committee’s judgement on the risks around the other conditioning assumptions set out in Section 1.1, including wholesale energy prices, to affect the calibration of the fan chart skew. If economic circumstances identical to today’s were to prevail on 100 occasions, the MPC’s best collective judgement is that inflation in any particular quarter would lie within the darkest central band on only 30 of those occasions. The fan chart is constructed so that outturns of inflation are also expected to lie within each pair of the lighter orange areas on 30 occasions. In any particular quarter of the forecast period, inflation is therefore expected to lie somewhere within the fans on 90 out of 100 occasions. And on the remaining 10 out of 100 occasions inflation can fall anywhere outside the orange area of the fan chart. Over the forecast period, this has been depicted by the grey background. See the Box on pages 48–49 of the May 2002 Inflation Report for a fuller description of the fan chart and what it represents.

Table 1.C: The quarterly modal projection for CPI inflation based on market rate expectations (a)

2024 Q3

2024 Q4

2025 Q1

2025 Q2

2025 Q3

CPI inflation

2.3

2.7

2.7

2.6

2.4

2025 Q4

2026 Q1

2026 Q2

2026 Q3

CPI inflation

2.2

2.0

1.7

1.7

2026 Q4

2027 Q1

2027 Q2

2027 Q3

CPI inflation

1.6

1.5

1.5

1.5

Footnotes

  • (a) Four-quarter inflation rate.

In the modal projection conditioned on the alternative assumption of constant interest rates at 5% over the forecast period, CPI inflation is expected to fall below 2% from 2025 Q4 onwards. This path is lower than the Committee’s modal projection conditioned on market rates.

The risks around the modal projection for CPI inflation are skewed somewhat to the upside, reflecting more persistence in domestic wage and price-setting.

There are upside risks to inflation from a more enduring shift in domestic price and wage-setting behaviour, perhaps associated with a higher medium-term equilibrium rate of unemployment. The possibility of some upside risks to demand or other downside risks to potential supply could, via a smaller margin of spare capacity in the economy and given a relatively tight starting point for the labour market, also motivate a higher medium-term profile for domestically generated inflation.

Acting in the other direction, the continued unwinding of the past shocks to energy and other imported goods prices may moderate the extent to which employees and domestic firms will seek higher nominal pay and domestic selling prices to recover the reductions in real incomes that they have experienced in the past. As headline CPI inflation and short-term inflation expectations have fallen further, inflationary dynamics could therefore adjust as rapidly on the downside as they did on the upside.

On balance, the risks around the modal projection for CPI inflation are judged to be skewed somewhat to the upside throughout the forecast period, reflecting more persistence in domestic wage and price setting. In turn this can be attributed to the upside risks around the modal output gap projection in this forecast in part related to the possibility of a higher equilibrium rate of unemployment (Key judgement 2).

The positive skew pushes up on the mean, relative to the modal, inflation projections in the forecast. Conditioned on market interest rates, mean CPI inflation is 2.0% and 1.8% at the two and three-year horizons respectively.

The risks around the modal projection for UK CPI inflation from international factors are more balanced. Although they have been higher than expected, developments in Chinese export prices could pose a downside risk to UK inflation if past weakness were to re-assert itself, particularly if that were to encourage other countries to reduce their export prices as well. Although there has so far been a relatively limited impact on trade and oil prices from events in the Middle East, there is a risk of further intensification over a longer period. The possibility of greater trade fragmentation and increased trade restrictions could also push up on world export prices.

Table 1.D: Indicative projections consistent with the MPC's modal forecast (a) (b)

Average 1998–2007

Average 2010–19

2022

2023

2024

2025

2026

World GDP (UK-weighted) (c)

3

3

2 (2)

2¼ (2)

2¼ (2¼)

World GDP (PPP-weighted) (d)

4

3 (3¼)

3 (3)

3 (3)

Euro-area GDP (e)

½

¾ (½)

1½ (1½)

1½ (1¾)

US GDP (f)

3

2

2½ (2¾)

2 (1½)

2 (2)

Emerging market GDP (PPP-weighted) (g)

5

4

4¼ (4¼)

4 (4)

4 (3¾)

  of which, China GDP (h)

10

3

4¾ (5¼)

4¼ (4¼)

4 (4)

UK GDP (i)

2

0

1¼ (½)

1 (1)

1¼ (1¼)

Household consumption (j)

2

5

¼

½ (¼)

1½ (1¼)

1¾ (1¾)

Business investment (k)

3

1 (0)

2¼ (1¼)

2 (3½)

Housing investment (l)

4

-7½

¾ (-4)

2¾ (-¼)

1½ (-1)

Exports (m)

9

-3¼ (2)

1¾ (1¼)

2¾ (1)

Imports (n)

6

4

14¾

-1½

-1½ (½)

4¼ (2½)

3¼ (2¼)

Contribution of net trade to GDP (o)

-1¾

¼

-½ (½)

-¾ (-½)

-¼ (-½)

Real post-tax labour income (p)

-2½

¾

3½ (3¼)

1½ (1¼)

½ (¼)

Household saving ratio (q)

11¾ (11)

11¼ (11)

10½ (9¾)

Credit spreads (r)

¾

1

¾

1 (1)

1¼ (1¼)

1½ (1½)

Excess supply/Excess demand (s)

0

-1¾

½

-¼ (-¼)

-¾ (-1)

-1¼ (-1¼)

Labour productivity (output per worker) (t)

¾

3

1½ (½)

¼ (½)

¾ (½)

Employment (u)

1

¼

0 (0)

¾ (½)

¾ (¾)

Working-age (16+) population (v)

¾

¾

1

¾

¾ (¾)

1 (1)

1 (1)

LFS unemployment rate (w)

6

4

4½ (4¼)

4¾ (4¾)

4¾ (4¾)

Participation rate (x)

63

63½

63

62¾

62¾ (62¾)

62½ (62½)

62½ (62½)

CPI inflation (y)

10¾

2¾ (2½)

2¼ (2¼)

1½ (1½)

UK import prices (z)

12½

½

-¾ (-1¾)

-1 (-¼)

-¼ (-¼)

Energy prices – direct contribution to CPI inflation (aa)

¼

¼

-1¼

-¼ (-¼)

0 (¼)

-¼ (-0)

Private sector regular average weekly earnings (AWE) (ab)

4

5 (5)

3 (3)

2¾ (2¾)

Private sector regular pay-based unit wage costs (ac)

2

7

7

2 (3¾)

3 (2¾)

1¾ (1¾)

Footnotes

  • Sources: Bank of England, Bloomberg Finance L.P., Department for Energy Security and Net Zero, Eurostat, IMF World Economic Outlook (WEO), National Bureau of Statistics of China, ONS, US Bureau of Economic Analysis and Bank calculations.
  • (a) The profiles in this table should be viewed as broadly consistent with the MPC’s modal projections for GDP growth, CPI inflation and unemployment (as presented in the fan charts). Staff have updated the set of profiles included here to align better with the data coverage in the wider Monetary Policy Report. The key changes relative to the table in the May 2024 Report are: the addition of population growth; the replacement of productivity growth (output per hour worked) with productivity growth (output per worker); the replacement of whole-economy average weekly earnings growth with private sector regular average weekly earnings growth; and the removal of real post-tax household income, average hours worked, and whole-economy unit labour cost growth.
  • (b) Figures show annual average growth rates unless otherwise stated. Figures in parentheses show the corresponding projections in the May 2024 Monetary Policy Report. Calculations for back data based on ONS data are shown using ONS series identifiers.
  • (c) Chained-volume measure. Constructed using real GDP growth rates of 188 countries weighted according to their shares in UK exports.
  • (d) Chained-volume measure. Constructed using real GDP growth rates of 189 countries weighted according to their shares in world GDP using the IMF’s purchasing power parity (PPP) weights.
  • (e) Chained-volume measure. The forecast was finalised before the release of the preliminary flash estimate of euro-area GDP for Q2, so that has not been incorporated.
  • (f) Chained-volume measure. The forecast was finalised before the release of the advance estimate of US GDP for Q2, so that has not been incorporated.
  • (g) Chained-volume measure. Constructed using real GDP growth rates of 155 emerging market economies, weighted according to their relative shares in world GDP using the IMF’s PPP weights.
  • (h) Chained-volume measure.
  • (i) Chained-volume measure.
  • (j) Chained-volume measure. Includes non-profit institutions serving households. Based on ABJR+HAYO.
  • (k) Chained-volume measure. Based on GAN8.
  • (l) Chained-volume measure. Whole-economy measure. Includes new dwellings, improvements and spending on services associated with the sale and purchase of property. Based on DFEG+L635+L637.
  • (m) Chained-volume measure. The historical data exclude the impact of missing trader intra‑community (MTIC) fraud. Since 1998 based on IKBK-OFNN/(BOKH/BQKO). Prior to 1998 based on IKBK.
  • (n) Chained-volume measure. The historical data exclude the impact of MTIC fraud. Since 1998 based on IKBL-OFNN/(BOKH/BQKO). Prior to 1998 based on IKBL.
  • (o) Chained-volume measure. Exports less imports.
  • (p) Wages and salaries plus mixed income and general government benefits less income taxes and employees’ National Insurance contributions, deflated by the consumer expenditure deflator. Based on [ROYJ+ROYH-(RPHS+AIIV-CUCT)+GZVX]/[(ABJQ+HAYE)/(ABJR+HAYO)]. The backdata for this series are available at Monetary Policy Report – Download chart slides and data – August 2024.
  • (q) Annual average. Percentage of total available household resources. Based on NRJS.
  • (r) Level in Q4. Percentage point spread over reference rates. Based on a weighted average of household and corporate loan and deposit spreads over appropriate risk-free rates. Indexed to equal zero in 2007 Q3.
  • (s) Annual average. Per cent of potential GDP. A negative figure implies output is below potential and a positive figure that it is above.
  • (t) Real GDP (ABMI) divided by total 16+ employment (MGRZ). Although LFS employment data have been re-instated by the ONS, they are badged as official statistics in development and the LFS continues to suffer from very low response rates, which can introduce volatility and potentially non-response bias (see Box D in the May 2024 Monetary Policy Report).
  • (u) Four-quarter growth in the ILO definition of employment in Q4 (MGRZ). Although LFS employment data have been re-instated by the ONS, they are badged as official statistics in development and the LFS continues to suffer from very low response rates, which can introduce volatility and potentially non-response bias (see Box D in the May 2024 Monetary Policy Report).
  • (v) Four-quarter growth in Q4. LFS household population, all aged 16 and over (MGSL). Growth rates are interpolated between the LFS and ONS National population projections: 2021-based interim within the forecast period.
  • (w) ILO definition of unemployment rate in Q4 (MGSX). Although LFS unemployment data have been re-instated by the ONS, they are badged as official statistics in development and the LFS continues to suffer from very low response rates, which can introduce volatility and potentially non-response bias (see Box D in the May 2024 Monetary Policy Report).
  • (x) ILO definition of labour force participation in Q4 as a percentage of the 16+ population (MGWG). Although LFS participation data have been re-instated by the ONS, they are badged as official statistics in development and the LFS continues to suffer from very low response rates, which can introduce volatility and potentially non-response bias (see Box D in the May 2024 Monetary Policy Report).
  • (y) Four-quarter inflation rate in Q4.
  • (z) Four-quarter inflation rate in Q4 excluding fuel and the impact of MTIC fraud.
  • (aa) Contribution of fuels and lubricants and gas and electricity prices to four-quarter CPI inflation in Q4.
  • (ab) Four-quarter growth in Q4. Private sector average weekly earnings excluding bonuses and arrears of pay (KAJ2).
  • (ac) Four-quarter growth in private sector regular pay-based unit wage costs in Q4. Private sector wage costs divided by private sector output at constant prices. Private sector wage costs are average weekly earnings (excluding bonuses) multiplied by private sector employment.

Box A: Reviewing the process of quantitative tightening

Since February 2022, the MPC has been reducing the stock of assets held in the Bank of England’s Asset Purchase Facility (APF) for monetary policy purposes, a process known as quantitative tightening (QT). In line with the commitment made by the MPC in the minutes of its August 2022 meeting, this box sets out the MPC’s annual assessment of QT over the past year. At its September 2024 meeting, the Committee will vote on the target for the reduction in the stock of UK government bonds held for monetary policy purposes over the 12-month period from October 2024 to September 2025.

Quantitative easing (QE) was introduced as part of the MPC’s policy response to the global financial crisis (GFC).

In the wake of the GFC, central banks around the world used a variety of monetary policy tools to meet their inflation targets and support economic activity. In the UK, Bank Rate was reduced to close to zero. To further stimulate the economy when interest rates were close to their effective lower bound, the point at which further cuts in the policy rate no longer provide stimulus, the MPC also began a programme of asset purchases, known as QE. Several rounds of QE have been conducted in the years since then. The stock of these purchases, made up of both government and corporate bonds, peaked at £895 billion in late 2021.

In 2022 the MPC began to reduce the stock of purchased assets in the APF.

Over the past few years, the MPC has increased Bank Rate in order to return CPI inflation sustainably to the 2% target. This has moved the policy rate away from its effective lower bound. In 2022, once Bank Rate had been raised to a level that provided scope to ease policy as required, the MPC commenced the process of running down holdings in the APF, also known as QT. This process has the benefit of reducing the risk of a ratchet upwards in the size of the Bank’s balance sheet over time, which in turn should increase the headroom and flexibility available to the Bank to use its balance sheet in the future if needed (Bailey et al (2020)).

The design of the MPC’s QT process has been guided by three key principles.

Prior to commencing QT, the MPC laid out the key principles that would guide its unwind strategy (see Box A of the August 2021 Report). The parameters of that strategy, agreed in 2022, are designed with these principles in mind.

First, the MPC intends to use Bank Rate as its active policy tool when adjusting the stance of monetary policy. The parameters of the QT strategy are amended at a lower frequency than decisions on Bank Rate and are not calibrated with a view to fine-tuning the monetary policy stance.

Second, sales are being conducted so as not to disrupt the functioning of financial markets, and only in appropriate market conditions.

Third, to help achieve that, sales are being conducted in a relatively gradual and predictable manner over a period of time.

By the end of September 2024, the APF will stand at £658 billion.

In February 2022, the Committee agreed to cease gilt reinvestments and begin sales of the sterling corporate bond portfolio. In September 2022, the Committee voted to reduce the stock of gilts held in the APF by £80 billion over October 2022–September 2023 and, in September 2023, by a further £100 billion over October 2023–September 2024. Because ceasing reinvestments alone would not have been sufficient to achieve the MPC’s target stock reduction, sales of gilts and corporate bonds were also conducted.

APF holdings of sterling non-financial investment-grade corporate bonds, which stood at £20 billion at their peak, have now been fully wound down. The final sales of corporate bonds occurred last year and a small number of shorter-maturity bonds matured in April of this year.

At the conclusion of the current 12-month gilt reduction programme in September, the APF will stand at £658 billion.

The latest analysis by Bank staff suggests that QT has had a small impact on gilt yields…

Following a further year’s worth of QT operations, Bank staff have updated their analysis of the effects of QT on gilt yields and the wider macroeconomy. While difficult to measure precisely, the impact of QT on gilt yields is judged to have been modest, in line with the evidence presented in Box A of the August 2023 Report.

One way to assess the impact of QT is through changes in UK term premia, the additional compensation investors demand to hold a longer-term bond relative to a series of shorter-term bonds. It is possible to decompose developments in gilt yields into those driven by estimated changes in the term premium, through which the effects of APF reduction are expected to operate, and those reflecting the expected path of policy rates. The 10-year gilt yield increased by around 275 basis points between February 2022 and June 2024 (Chart A). Within that, the term premium (orange bars) is estimated to have risen by around 75 basis points over the same period.

QT is likely to account for only a small part of the 75 basis points estimated rise in the term premium, which is influenced by a range of factors including uncertainty around the outlook for the economy and interest rates, and gilt supply and demand. Modelling work by Bank staff that attempts to isolate the impact of QT-related announcements and auctions suggests that APF reduction accounts for only around 10–20 basis points of the total rise in the term premium. Bank staff judge 10 basis points to be the central case estimate, while 20 basis points is considered to be a conservative upper bound. Market participants have suggested an impact of similar magnitude. The effects of APF gilt sales and maturities are judged to be similar.

Chart A: The term premium accounts for only a small part of the rise in gilt yields since early 2022

Decomposition of the UK 10-year government bond yield (a)

The term premium accounts for only a small proportion of the increase in the 10-year gilt yield since the February 2022 MPC meeting. The majority of the increase in gilt yields has been driven by an increase in expected rates.

Footnotes

  • Sources: Bloomberg Finance L.P., Tradeweb and Bank calculations.
  • (a) The numbers in the chart are based on estimates from a range of internal models of UK term premia, which split the 10-year gilt yield into expected rates and term premia contributions. Expected rates reflect investors’ expectations of the average short-term monetary policy rate over the next 10 years, and the term premium is defined as the additional compensation investors demand to hold a longer-term bond relative to a series of shorter-term bonds.

Event study analysis, which seeks to isolate the impact of QT by focusing on movements in asset prices during short windows around announcements and auctions, also points to a small impact. Daily movements in a range of financial market measures have been a little more volatile on QT announcement days. But since QT announcements typically coincide with communications about wider MPC decisions, this additional volatility cannot be wholly attributed to QT. The same approach suggests no material difference in volatility between QT auction and non-auction days, consistent with the MPC’s intention that sales should happen in a gradual and predictable manner. Further to that, analysis by Bank staff suggests that any impact of QT auctions on 10-year gilt yields has tended to fade entirely within one day.

…and QT operations have had little impact on market functioning.

Measures of gilt market liquidity have, if anything, improved since the start of QT, with some signs that sales may in fact have had a positive effect by alleviating collateral scarcity at shorter maturities. As such, there is little evidence of a negative impact of gilt sales on market functioning across a range of financial market measures. In particular, the gilt market appears to be functioning well.

These findings are broadly consistent with those from other empirical studies and central banks.

There is a growing body of research examining the possible effects of QT on government bond yields, with conclusions broadly consistent with Bank staff’s analysis. In one example, Du et al (2024) find that several cross-country QT programmes have been successfully run with minimal impact on market functioning and liquidity. Their analysis also suggests that the impact of QT on yields has been fairly small.

Several other central banks have begun winding down their stocks of purchased assets in recent years. Because of differences in operating frameworks and approaches to portfolio reduction, international experiences are not directly comparable. However, evidence from other central banks suggests that, while QT has led to some tightening across financial market indicators, that tightening effect has been relatively small.

The impact of QT on the real economy is also judged to have been small.

All else equal, the tightening effect of QT on yields would be expected to feed through to lower economic activity and inflation. It remains too early to assess this broader impact, but based on the UK’s experience of QE, a 10 basis points increase in yields would be associated with a negative impact on GDP and inflation of less than 0.2% and 0.1 percentage points respectively. To the extent that these effects are priced into asset markets, they will feed into the MPC’s projections and policy assessments via the conditioning assumptions on which the projections are based.

The tightening impact of APF reduction is expected to be smaller than the stimulus associated with QE. That is partly because, as noted in Box A of the August 2021 Report, increasing the target stock of purchased assets may have provided a signal about the need for a looser stance of monetary policy. By contrast, QT has been conducted in an environment in which Bank Rate is the active monetary policy tool and so the process of APF reduction does not signal a need for a higher path for Bank Rate. In addition, QE was at times deliberately conducted during periods of market stress in order to improve liquidity and market functioning. By contrast, the reduction of holdings in the APF is being undertaken only in appropriate market conditions and in a gradual and predictable manner.

Given the limited economic impact associated with a gradual pace of reduction, the effects of QT can be offset with small adjustments in Bank Rate.

Any tightening effect on the macroeconomy from a reduction in the APF would require a slightly lower path for Bank Rate, all else equal. As described above, the MPC takes account of these anticipated effects from QT when taking decisions on Bank Rate, to the extent that the asset prices on which the MPC’s economic projections and policy assessments are conditioned incorporate announced and expected APF reductions. That said, given that a gradual pace of APF reduction is expected to have a limited economic impact, any required adjustments in Bank Rate are likely to be very small. Consistent with that, there was no clear relationship between expectations for Bank Rate and the path of QT among responses to the Bank’s July Market Participants Survey, indicating that the MPC’s QT principles are working as intended.

The market path for interest rates, on which the MPC’s August MPR projections are conditioned, implies a reduction in Bank Rate to 3½% by 2027 Q3 (Section 1). The MPC expects that the impact of QT – and hence the implications for the appropriate path for Bank Rate – will remain small as the policy rate is reduced. That is consistent with Bank Rate being the active tool of monetary policy and QT operating in the background.

So far, in the UK, QT has been conducted while Bank Rate has been increased or kept unchanged. There is therefore a degree of uncertainty about the interaction between these tools during periods in which Bank Rate is being reduced. In the unlikely event that the tightening impact of QT was larger than expected, the distance of Bank Rate from its effective lower bound provides scope for reductions to be made if policy needed to be loosened to offset the effect on the real economy. Nevertheless, the Committee will continue to monitor closely the interaction between these tools.

The appropriate pace of total gilt stock reduction will continue to be guided by the MPC’s key principles.

As has been the case up to this point, the MPC’s key principles and analysis of the first few years of APF unwind will be central to its judgement on the appropriate pace of gilt stock reduction over the year ahead.

At its September meeting the Committee will vote on the target for the reduction in the stock of UK government bonds held for monetary policy purposes over the 12-month period from October 2024 to September 2025. Bank Rate remains the MPC’s active tool of monetary policy and will be set to meet the 2% inflation target sustainably in the medium term.

Chart B: APF maturities and sales since APF reduction began and maturities in future gilt stock reduction periods (a) (b)

Over October 2022 to September 2023 and October 2023 to September 2024 APF cash flows have been £100 billion. Over the next 12 month period, maturities increase to around £90 billion, before falling back over subsequent periods.

Footnotes

  • Source: Bank calculations.
  • (a) Each year shows maturities in the period between October and September of the following year (ie a yearly QT review cycle). For October 2022–September 2023 and October 2023–September 2024 these bars show the target gilt stock reduction voted for by the MPC, including both maturities and active sales. In periods from October 2024–September 2025 onwards only the path of expected maturities is shown, as the Committee is yet to vote on the target gilt stock reduction for these periods.
  • (b) The amount of APF stock reduction set by the MPC is expressed in terms of the initial proceeds paid to purchase the APF holdings.

Box B: Monetary policy since the May 2024 Report

At its meeting ending on 19 June 2024, the MPC voted by a majority of 7–2 to maintain Bank Rate at 5.25%. Two members preferred to reduce Bank Rate by 0.25 percentage points, to 5%.

Since the MPC’s previous meeting, 12-month CPI inflation had fallen to 2.0% in May from 3.2% in March, close to the May Monetary Policy Report projection. Indicators of short-term inflation expectations had also continued to moderate, particularly for households. CPI inflation was expected to rise slightly in the second half of this year, as declines in energy prices last year fall out of the annual comparison.

UK GDP appeared to have grown more strongly than expected during the first half of this year. Business surveys, however, remained consistent with a slower pace of underlying growth, of around ¼% per quarter.

The considerable uncertainty around estimates derived from the ONS Labour Force Survey made it very difficult to gauge the evolution of labour market activity. Based on a broad set of indicators, the MPC judged that the labour market continued to loosen but that it remained relatively tight by historical standards.

The collective steer from a range of indicators of aggregate pay growth had continued to ease in the latest data. Services consumer price inflation was 5.7% in May, down from 6.0% in March, but somewhat higher than projected in the May Report. This strength in part reflected prices that are index-linked or regulated, which are typically changed only annually, and volatile components.

Headline CPI inflation had fallen back to the 2% target. The restrictive stance of monetary policy was weighing on activity in the real economy, leading to a looser labour market and bearing down on inflationary pressures. Key indicators of inflation persistence had continued to moderate, although they remained elevated.

Monetary policy would need to remain restrictive for sufficiently long to return inflation to the 2% target sustainably in the medium term in line with the MPC’s remit. The Committee had judged since last autumn that monetary policy needed to be restrictive for an extended period of time until the risk of inflation becoming embedded above the 2% target dissipated.

The MPC remained prepared to adjust monetary policy as warranted by economic data to return inflation to the 2% target sustainably. It would therefore continue to monitor closely indications of persistent inflationary pressures and resilience in the economy as a whole, including a range of measures of the underlying tightness of labour market conditions, wage growth and services price inflation. As part of the August forecast round, members of the Committee would consider all of the information available and how this affected the assessment that the risks from inflation persistence were receding. On that basis, the Committee would keep under review for how long Bank Rate should be maintained at its current level.

2: Current economic conditions

UK-weighted global activity is expected to grow by around 2% over 2024. Global export price inflation is projected to pick up gradually. Headline consumer price inflation has fallen across advanced economies over the past year or so, but services price inflation remains high. The market-implied paths are consistent with reductions in policy rates across advanced economies. Sterling has appreciated by 2½% since the May Report.

Following weakness in the second half of 2023, UK GDP growth picked up quite sharply around the turn of the year and has been stronger than expected in the May Report. Underlying momentum in activity is judged to be somewhat weaker than the headline figures suggest, however, and GDP growth is expected to fall back in Q3.

Despite the recent strength in GDP, aggregate demand and supply remain in balance. The UK labour market has continued to ease, although it remains relatively tight by historical standards. Large uncertainties remain around the LFS labour market statistics. Bank staff’s indicator-based models suggest that employment growth has remained positive but modest. Unemployment is expected to rise slightly in coming quarters reflecting the continued restrictive stance of monetary policy.

CPI inflation has fallen further since the May Report and was at the MPC’s 2% target in May and June. Within that, goods price inflation was slightly negative, reflecting past declines in external cost pressures, while services price inflation remained elevated at 5.7%. Headline CPI inflation is projected to rise to around 2¾% by the end of the year, owing largely to a smaller drag on annual inflation from domestic energy bills. The fading drag from energy prices on headline CPI inflation reveals the persistence in services price inflation, which is expected to remain elevated in coming quarters due to continued strength in wage growth.

Annual private sector regular average weekly earnings (AWE) growth has fallen back since mid-2023 but remained elevated at 5.6% in the three months to May. Falls in short-term inflation expectations and the loosening in the labour market mean that wage growth is expected to fall further in the near term, to just under 5% in 2024 Q3, but to remain elevated relative to the past.

Chart 2.1: In the MPC’s latest projections, GDP growth remains strong before falling back, the unemployment rate is flat, and CPI inflation rises moderately in the second half of this year

Near-term projections (a)